Supply-side Believers
The two most important pillars of Ronald Reagan’s presidency were his arms build up to counter Soviet aggression and his implementation of supply-side economic theory.
The two most important pillars of Ronald Reagan’s presidency were
his arms build up to counter Soviet aggression and his implementation
of supply-side economic theory. At the time, supply-side theory —
cutting marginal tax rates to increase economic growth — was considered
reckless. But after a generation of success, the unorthodox approach became
orthodox. Keynesian economics — stimulating demand through government
spending — was the dominant economic theory of the post-war age
of liberalism, and it seemed archaic in the new age.
The era of supply-side economics began in 1974 when its champion, Arthur
Laffer, had dinner at a Washington, D.C., restaurant with President Ford’s
chief of staff and deputy chief of staff, Don Rumsfeld and Dick Cheney,
along with former Wall Street Journal associate editor, Jude Wanniski.
Writes Laffer about the dinner, “While discussing President Ford’s
‘WIN’ (Whip Inflation Now) proposal for tax increases, I supposedly
grabbed my napkin and a pen and sketched a curve on the napkin illustrating
the trade-off between tax rates and tax revenues. Wanniski named the trade-off
the ‘Laffer Curve.’”
The successful implementation of the Laffer Curve took place during the
Reagan years and, for the most part, was not repealed during the Clinton
administration. It was tried again successfully during the first six years
of George W. Bush’s administration. However, during the last few
years, even before the 2008 financial crisis, supply-side economics began
to pick up some influential critics, including Warren Buffet and Financial
Times columnists Larry Summers and Samuel Brittan.
America’s most recent period of economic expansion from 2001-2007
saw record corporate profits while incomes remained flat or declined.
The recent expansion was the first in the post-war era in which incomes
did not keep pace with corporate profits. Why? The question has bothered
many economists. Why did incomes remain flat, especially since unemployment
figures were at historically low rates? Why was wealth more concentrated
in the top 20 percent of Americans than any other time in a century? Was
it because of technology breakthroughs in the 1990s? Did the IT revolution
not have enough time to trickle down? Was it globalization? Were global
profits kept by corporate leaders while production was spread more evenly
across the world? When answers weren’t definitive, patience waned
among policymakers for an economic theory that had promised all would
benefit when marginal tax rates were lowered.
“All economic ideas are a reflection of the times in which they
are born,” says Phil Romero, dean of the College of Business and
Economics for California State University, Los Angeles. Keynesian economics
came out of a time when the orthodoxy was that economies were self-correcting,
which was the way Hoover played his term in office.
“Keynes realized that when demand falls too far below supply you
need someone with big pockets to stimulate the economy — big pockets
like the government. It worked well for a generation. By 1960, economists
thought they could fine tune the economy and eliminate recessions. But
confidence turned to hubris when LBJ ran large deficits and devalued the
dollar, accelerating inflation,” says Romero.
Toss in a couple of oil shocks in the 1970s and Americans entered a decade
of stagflation where stopping inflation meant slowing the economy, and
stimulating the economy meant debasing the currency. Enter supply-side
economics and the Laffer Curve. “Supply-side worked like a charm
for 20 years,” says Romero, “from the early 1980s to 2000.”
The strengths of the theory began to wind down this decade when a world
savings glut brought a period of low interest rates, a negative yield
curve and then, of course, the housing bubble. “The bubble in this
decade was inflated by foreign savings, foreign ownership of American
assets. And as the federal government and some states borrow more and
more, that will just accelerate that trend,” says Romero. “In
the long run those governments will have to reverse course and run surpluses
and that will mean higher taxes.”
Tim Duy, University of Oregon economics professor and author of the Oregon
Index of Economic Indicators, is not a fan of supply-side economics, and
he doesn’t believe in the Laffer Curve. “Reagan proved that
deficits don’t matter, especially if Japan and China were willing
to buy up the debt — that made everything work for 25 years.”
Duy, like a growing school of economists, believes that it was Clinton’s
economic choices, not supply-side theory, that caused America to run a
budget surplus in the late 1990s. “None of the bad things that people
expected from the deficits of the 1980s occurred because of Clinton and
the IT industry,” says Duy. “Clinton partially raised taxes
and the IT boom drove revenue growth, and after the GOP took control of
Congress, there were no substantial spending opportunities.”
So what’s gone wrong in this decade? It wouldn’t be a stretch
to say that Duy partially blames it on a return to supply-side theory
under President George W. Bush. “Most people are willing to admit
that median incomes have not kept up with GDP growth,” he says.
“A huge amount of benefits have accrued to a relatively small population.”
Duy then asks some tough questions about supply-side economics that pertain
to this decade. “How does wealth become concentrated? How do policies
encourage wealth concentration? What kind of tax cuts do that?”
Duy takes his criticism of supply-side economics beyond tax policy to
a broader condemnation of past policies. “I believe that runaway
global capital flows, where there is a propensity for China to manage
them while we won’t, have distorted global patterns of production
and consumption.”
This view, which is becoming more and more popular, is a fancy way of
saying that Americans don’t manufacture products anymore. As a result
of what Duy calls runaway capital flows, he now believes that the case
for free trade has been undermined.
Ralph Shaw, former chairman of the Governor’s Council of Economic
Advisors in Oregon, is more bullish about supply-side economics. “Supply-side
economics worked for over 20 years and worked well,” says Shaw.
“It opened up opportunities in areas that had not previously been
developed.” But he adds, “Like every theory, when it works
for a long time we lose our sense of fear that demands that we do our
homework and think rationally.”
Shaw has been through a couple of economic bubbles and downturns in his
life. He doesn’t blame our recent trouble on supply-side theory,
but rather on the inevitable screw-ups of human nature.
“Providing capital to the private sector leads to the development
of adequate supply and then leads to excess supply, as people believe
they don’t have to do the homework of matching future demand with
future supply. What you have,” says Shaw, “is people who see
a trend analysis that shows certain areas of the economy growing quickly.
Then consultants read this and bring investors and companies into those
sectors. Industries often use irrational thought and analysis. No economic
philosophy can legislate an absence of greed or shallow thinking.”
As for incomes not growing in the last decade, Shaw doesn’t blame
it on supply-side theory or globalization, but on our educational system
instead.
“A third of our students who enter high school are not graduating.
How can you expect that one-third to contribute enough to the economy
that they can make a real economic contribution and achieve a good standard
of living?”
As for the current Keynesian mantra? “Keynesian economics does
have a place — all this money will lead to increased demand,”
says Shaw. “It will lead to products, roads. And changes related
to Keynesian theory will bring mortgages down and make homes available,
and then people will measure the cost and look at going forward. It will
also lead to very high budget deficits and the declining value of the
U.S. dollar, but that won’t be the topic until this very serious
recession is done.”
Romero, having been an occasional lunch partner of Arthur Laffer, also
remains a believer in supply-side economics, with this caveat. “Every
economic school that’s sensible has its place in certain historical
circumstances. Keynesian economics is necessary during deep recessions,
and supply-side economics is what you should be doing in between those
recessions.”
Written by Jim Pasero
|